Reforming the Urban Water System in Santiago, Chile

In the late 1980s, Chile planned to privatize Santiago's sanitary works enterprise (EMOS) but instead reformed it under public ownership. It did so through a regulatory framework that mimicked the design of a concession with a private utility,...

Full description

Bibliographic Details
Main Authors: Shirley, Mary M., Xu, L. Colin, Zuluaga, Ana Maria
Format: Working Paper
Language:English
en_US
Published: World Bank, Washington, DC 2015
Subjects:
Online Access:http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/2000/03/438162/reforming-urban-water-system-santiago-chile
http://hdl.handle.net/10986/22314
id okr-10986-22314
recordtype oai_dc
spelling okr-10986-223142021-04-23T14:04:07Z Reforming the Urban Water System in Santiago, Chile Shirley, Mary M. Xu, L. Colin Zuluaga, Ana Maria CASH FLOW CONCESSION AREA CONSTRUCTION CONSUMER SURPLUS CONTAMINATED WATER COST RECOVERY DEBT DEMAND ESTIMATES DEMAND FOR WATER DIVIDENDS ECONOMIC EFFECTS ECONOMIC WELFARE EXPENDITURES FIXED COSTS HIGH LEVELS HOUSEHOLDS INCOME INFLATION INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE INVESTMENT PROGRAM INVESTMENT REQUIREMENTS MARGINAL COSTS MUNICIPAL COMPANIES MUNICIPAL COMPANY MUNICIPALITIES NUMBER OF CONNECTIONS PIPED WATER POPULATION GROWTH PRICE OF WATER PRIVATE PROPERTY PRIVATE UTILITY PRIVATE WATER RIGHTS PRODUCTIVITY PUBLIC MANAGEMENT PUBLIC OWNERSHIP PUBLIC WATER PUBLIC WORKS RAW WATER REGULATORY FRAMEWORK SALE OF WATER SERVICE QUALITY SEWAGE TREATMENT SEWERAGE SERVICES SNOW MELT SURFACE WATER TARIFF DECISIONS TARIFF SETTING TARIFF SETTING PROCESS TRANSACTION COSTS URBAN WATER URBAN WATER SUPPLY URBAN WATER SYSTEM UTILITIES VARIABLE COSTS WAGES WASTEWATER WATER COMPANIES WATER COMPANY WATER CONNECTIONS WATER CONSUMPTION WATER INFRASTRUCTURE WATER LEGISLATION WATER MARKET WATER PRESSURE WATER REGULATION WATER RIGHTS WATER SECTOR WATER SERVICES WATER SHORTAGES WATER SOURCES WATER SYSTEM WATER SYSTEMS WATER TARIFFS WELFARE GAINS WELLS In the late 1980s, Chile planned to privatize Santiago's sanitary works enterprise (EMOS) but instead reformed it under public ownership. It did so through a regulatory framework that mimicked the design of a concession with a private utility, setting tariffs that ensured at least a seven percent return on assets, creating a neutral regulator independent of ministry intervention, and giving EMOS the right to appeal the regulator's tariff decisions. This reform of Santiago's water system is often cited as a case of successful reform under public management. Comparing a comprehensive measure of welfare with a counterfactual example, the authors show surprisingly large gains from Santiago's reform, given the relatively good initial conditions. (The gains accrued largely to government and employees, but consumers benefited from improved service and coverage). Why did reform in Santiago improve water system performance, when similar reform attempts under public management in other countries failed? 1) Chile has a long tradition of private water rights, shaped by early recognition that water is a scarce and tradable private good. 2) The reformed regulatory framework was designed to attract private investors to the water system and to motivate them to operate efficiently and expand the system. 3) Chile's unique electoral institutions sustained this framework under state operation after democracy was restored. 4) Chile's strong bureaucratic norms and institutions (permitting little corruption), combined with Santiago's relatively low-cost water system, permitted prices that effectively increased quasi-rents for investing in the system while minimizing the risk of inefficiency or monopoly rents. The authors also address the question of why EMOS was reformed but not privatized, and what the costs of not privatizing were. The system was privatized in 1999, but the changes from privatization are likely to be less significant than those introduced in 1989-90. 2015-07-28T18:30:00Z 2015-07-28T18:30:00Z 2000-03 Working Paper http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/2000/03/438162/reforming-urban-water-system-santiago-chile http://hdl.handle.net/10986/22314 English en_US Policy Research Working Paper;No. 2294 CC BY 3.0 IGO http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0/igo/ World Bank World Bank, Washington, DC Publications & Research Publications & Research :: Policy Research Working Paper Latin America & Caribbean South America Chile
repository_type Digital Repository
institution_category Foreign Institution
institution Digital Repositories
building World Bank Open Knowledge Repository
collection World Bank
language English
en_US
topic CASH FLOW
CONCESSION AREA
CONSTRUCTION
CONSUMER SURPLUS
CONTAMINATED WATER
COST RECOVERY
DEBT
DEMAND ESTIMATES
DEMAND FOR WATER
DIVIDENDS
ECONOMIC EFFECTS
ECONOMIC WELFARE
EXPENDITURES
FIXED COSTS
HIGH LEVELS
HOUSEHOLDS
INCOME
INFLATION
INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES
INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE
INVESTMENT PROGRAM
INVESTMENT REQUIREMENTS
MARGINAL COSTS
MUNICIPAL COMPANIES
MUNICIPAL COMPANY
MUNICIPALITIES
NUMBER OF CONNECTIONS
PIPED WATER
POPULATION GROWTH
PRICE OF WATER
PRIVATE PROPERTY
PRIVATE UTILITY
PRIVATE WATER RIGHTS
PRODUCTIVITY
PUBLIC MANAGEMENT
PUBLIC OWNERSHIP
PUBLIC WATER
PUBLIC WORKS
RAW WATER
REGULATORY FRAMEWORK
SALE OF WATER
SERVICE QUALITY
SEWAGE TREATMENT
SEWERAGE SERVICES
SNOW MELT
SURFACE WATER
TARIFF DECISIONS
TARIFF SETTING
TARIFF SETTING PROCESS
TRANSACTION COSTS
URBAN WATER
URBAN WATER SUPPLY
URBAN WATER SYSTEM
UTILITIES
VARIABLE COSTS
WAGES
WASTEWATER
WATER COMPANIES
WATER COMPANY
WATER CONNECTIONS
WATER CONSUMPTION
WATER INFRASTRUCTURE
WATER LEGISLATION
WATER MARKET
WATER PRESSURE
WATER REGULATION
WATER RIGHTS
WATER SECTOR
WATER SERVICES
WATER SHORTAGES
WATER SOURCES
WATER SYSTEM
WATER SYSTEMS
WATER TARIFFS
WELFARE GAINS
WELLS
spellingShingle CASH FLOW
CONCESSION AREA
CONSTRUCTION
CONSUMER SURPLUS
CONTAMINATED WATER
COST RECOVERY
DEBT
DEMAND ESTIMATES
DEMAND FOR WATER
DIVIDENDS
ECONOMIC EFFECTS
ECONOMIC WELFARE
EXPENDITURES
FIXED COSTS
HIGH LEVELS
HOUSEHOLDS
INCOME
INFLATION
INFORMATION ASYMMETRIES
INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE
INVESTMENT PROGRAM
INVESTMENT REQUIREMENTS
MARGINAL COSTS
MUNICIPAL COMPANIES
MUNICIPAL COMPANY
MUNICIPALITIES
NUMBER OF CONNECTIONS
PIPED WATER
POPULATION GROWTH
PRICE OF WATER
PRIVATE PROPERTY
PRIVATE UTILITY
PRIVATE WATER RIGHTS
PRODUCTIVITY
PUBLIC MANAGEMENT
PUBLIC OWNERSHIP
PUBLIC WATER
PUBLIC WORKS
RAW WATER
REGULATORY FRAMEWORK
SALE OF WATER
SERVICE QUALITY
SEWAGE TREATMENT
SEWERAGE SERVICES
SNOW MELT
SURFACE WATER
TARIFF DECISIONS
TARIFF SETTING
TARIFF SETTING PROCESS
TRANSACTION COSTS
URBAN WATER
URBAN WATER SUPPLY
URBAN WATER SYSTEM
UTILITIES
VARIABLE COSTS
WAGES
WASTEWATER
WATER COMPANIES
WATER COMPANY
WATER CONNECTIONS
WATER CONSUMPTION
WATER INFRASTRUCTURE
WATER LEGISLATION
WATER MARKET
WATER PRESSURE
WATER REGULATION
WATER RIGHTS
WATER SECTOR
WATER SERVICES
WATER SHORTAGES
WATER SOURCES
WATER SYSTEM
WATER SYSTEMS
WATER TARIFFS
WELFARE GAINS
WELLS
Shirley, Mary M.
Xu, L. Colin
Zuluaga, Ana Maria
Reforming the Urban Water System in Santiago, Chile
geographic_facet Latin America & Caribbean
South America
Chile
relation Policy Research Working Paper;No. 2294
description In the late 1980s, Chile planned to privatize Santiago's sanitary works enterprise (EMOS) but instead reformed it under public ownership. It did so through a regulatory framework that mimicked the design of a concession with a private utility, setting tariffs that ensured at least a seven percent return on assets, creating a neutral regulator independent of ministry intervention, and giving EMOS the right to appeal the regulator's tariff decisions. This reform of Santiago's water system is often cited as a case of successful reform under public management. Comparing a comprehensive measure of welfare with a counterfactual example, the authors show surprisingly large gains from Santiago's reform, given the relatively good initial conditions. (The gains accrued largely to government and employees, but consumers benefited from improved service and coverage). Why did reform in Santiago improve water system performance, when similar reform attempts under public management in other countries failed? 1) Chile has a long tradition of private water rights, shaped by early recognition that water is a scarce and tradable private good. 2) The reformed regulatory framework was designed to attract private investors to the water system and to motivate them to operate efficiently and expand the system. 3) Chile's unique electoral institutions sustained this framework under state operation after democracy was restored. 4) Chile's strong bureaucratic norms and institutions (permitting little corruption), combined with Santiago's relatively low-cost water system, permitted prices that effectively increased quasi-rents for investing in the system while minimizing the risk of inefficiency or monopoly rents. The authors also address the question of why EMOS was reformed but not privatized, and what the costs of not privatizing were. The system was privatized in 1999, but the changes from privatization are likely to be less significant than those introduced in 1989-90.
format Working Paper
author Shirley, Mary M.
Xu, L. Colin
Zuluaga, Ana Maria
author_facet Shirley, Mary M.
Xu, L. Colin
Zuluaga, Ana Maria
author_sort Shirley, Mary M.
title Reforming the Urban Water System in Santiago, Chile
title_short Reforming the Urban Water System in Santiago, Chile
title_full Reforming the Urban Water System in Santiago, Chile
title_fullStr Reforming the Urban Water System in Santiago, Chile
title_full_unstemmed Reforming the Urban Water System in Santiago, Chile
title_sort reforming the urban water system in santiago, chile
publisher World Bank, Washington, DC
publishDate 2015
url http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/2000/03/438162/reforming-urban-water-system-santiago-chile
http://hdl.handle.net/10986/22314
_version_ 1764450609228939264